Deregulation has taken a lot of the blame for the current crisis. Most of the people saying that conclude that if deregulation caused the problem, regulation can solve it. They are wrong.
To understand why you must abandon the common, if largely unconscious assumptions about regulatiors and how they produce regulation. Generally people assume that wise, impartial regulators sit down, look objectively at the facts and, unswayed by intellectual fashion and the irrational exuberance or depression of the market and society, make wise, impartial, objectively based decisions. If that were true then why is it that such decisions are only made exactly when they are not needed, as is presently happening. Currently the US government is writing rules about overextending your company, investing too much in doubtful financial assets and everything nobody wants to do any more because it loses money. No doubt other governments are too. It's like making sure everyone has cleaned the leaves out of their gutters after a bushfire has demolished half the town. To understand why they're passing such laws and regulations now, you must understand the financial regulatory cycle and how it trails the monetary cycle.
Stage one of the regulatory cycle is Crisis, caused by the excesses of monetary expansion. Crisis creates a demand for immediate action to combat the cause of the present catastrophe. The cause is however the state of the regulatory cycle some time in the past so correcting it has no immediate effect.
Nevertheless the second stage, Action occurs. Regardless of the immediate effects of Action the monetary cycle moves on and things correct themselves. The Action may speed this up, slow it down, make it easier or harder, more expensive or cheaper.
This leads to the third stage, Inefficency. During Inefficency actions taken during more frantic times are observed to be hampering the markets efforts to create wealth. Since the market is still in recovering from a bust there is little chance they are actually preventing bad behaviour anyway, since that only happens in the boom phase. Thus their effect is to impose large present costs for very small or nonexistant present gains.
This leads to the fourth stage, Circumvention. Firms in the financial market do two things. Lobbying to remove the restrictions placed in stage 2 occurs to the general appathy of the population. Few if any voters and political masters understand the present rules and why or even if they're important. Resistance to selective deregulation is low as the circumstances that led to the need for the regulation are gone. Firms also develop practices that go around the current rules while having largely the same effects as the practices forbidden. This makes the original regulations even less important, even counterproductive if they simply shift activity to less transparent or accountable sections of the economy. Circumvention accelerates when during times of monetary expansion because during those time the need for caution and restraint is weakest.
The combination of the monetary boom and Circumvention above leads back to Crisis.
You might ask, "Is this cycle inevitable?". Might we act appropriately and promptly to prevent such a destructive turn of events. The answer is "Why would we?". During the times when such action is neccesary by it's nature few people think it's warrented. If people were in general worried about the negative effects of asset price bubble then we would not have one, since a precondition of such a boom is that people don't think it's either happening or going to happen. To impose or keep regulations to prevent it happening regulators must go against the wishes of pretty much everyone who's paying attention to their activities. They must do this despite not being able to offer any evidence that their actions are warranted, predictions being notoriously difficult in economics. Those wanting to remove restrictions can point to solid evidence of costs in the here and now. In any case in many or even most cases they're right about the high costs and low benefits of regulation, because much of the regulation was passed in panic during stage 2 (Action) when it was felt there was little time to think through the costs and problems. A case could and will be made that the actions in the Action stage were hasty and ill-considered and possibly now out of date. A general mood of caution and pessimism will defeat this case, which is another way of saying regulation won't be abandoned until shortly before it's needed.
And yes, my blogposts are like buses, none for yonks then three come at once.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
3 comments:
A lot of the problems government has in this area stems from the fact are the very idea that you can reliably predict the outcome, or post facto see the results of an intervention or policy is pretty ridiculous. This is especially so when it comes to an agency like a political bureaucracy, whose very existence is oriented towards intervention; whose success basically depends on selecting pro-regulation people and generating a pro-regulation atmosphere. Contra many economists who seem to assume that regulators know anything about economics (or that they are likely to see Austrian economics as a credible source), politicians and bureaucrats don't know what they don't know. What's more - giving any sort of meaningfully predictive assessment of sugar tariffs etc. - is something pretty much no one does, or could, know.
It doesn't really matter whether regulators or politiicans reliably predict the outcome or even think they can. They'll do it anyway because they're slaves to opinion, both of the general public and interested parties. They don't have the de facto power to leave well enough or bad enough alone. In fact economists make pretty accurate assessments of the effects of tariffs all the time. They're gathering dust in a forgotten government drawer as we speak.
"It doesn't really matter whether regulators or politiicans reliably predict the outcome or even think they can."
While this is somewhat true, remember that people within the bureaucracy are in an agency which assumes itself useful, there is a huge system of incentive, information bias and selection bias which often precludes them taking the advice of economists seriously as they will always have 'experts' on hand who feel exactly the opposite, and it is these sorts of experts who get employed at regulatory agencies to begin with.
What's more, by 'reliable prediction' I do not mean making general statements of economic necessity (the law of marginal utility, or non-contradiction for that matter). I mean making specific statements which would be required for things like assessing relative scarcity and making comparisons of opportunity costs. Likewise with assessing the 'gains' and 'losses' post facto. While an economist may be able to tell them their actions involve the broken window fallacy, even he is in no position to make feasible, accurate assessments of who gained and loss as a result of specific administrative action. When this includes a 'policy' affecting hundreds of millions of people, it becomes even more ridiculous to pretend to have answers to whether the situation has gotten better or worse from anyone's perspective as a result of the policy.
See Jeffrey Friedman on Bureaucracy, also the problem with 'Rational Ignorance' theories.
http://www.criticalreview.com/crf/jeffreyfriedman.html
Post a Comment